Quotes, data and comments: The Coal Question by Stanley Jevons
This great book is underrated for two reasons. First, neoclassic economists don't want to mention this book because the ideas are not consistent with today's neoclassical theory. Second, non-neoclassical people don't want to read it because it was written by the founder of neoclassical economics. This book is the first systematic exposition of biophysical economic theory and the most comprehensive study of the implication of the energy use.
The hallmark of a great research is to ask the most
important question. Jevons apparently got it right to ask The Coal Question.
This is why he could offer such clear explanation of so many fundamental
problems in
From reading the preface, I can see that the same oppositions to Jevons’ ideas will come back again. Those who argue against us don’t have to provide anything concrete. They only have to mention “technology progress”.
To anyone who shares the views expressed by Jevons, on the supreme importance of coal in relation to industrial development, the advance of Germany, like that of the United States, will appear to have resulted from the natural conditions of the territory occupied by an energetic and intelligent race, rather than from the conditions created by legislatures. (p. xv)
Since the relation between efficiency and total consumption is a very important topic today, we would benefit from reviewing his ideas on this topic.
But persons will commit a great oversight here if they overlook the cost of an improved and complicated engine, which both in its first cost and its maintenance, is higher than that of a simple one. The question is one of capital against current expenditure. (p. xxxv)
It is wholly a confusion of ideas to suppose that the economic use of fuel is equivalent to a diminished consumption. The very contrary is the truth. As a rule, new modes of economy will lead to an increase of consumption according to a principle recognized in many parallel instances. (p. 140)
Most articles citing Jevons would say that people will use more when a system becomes more efficient. But the reality is that people have to use more when a system becomes more efficient. I will use an example to illustrate it.
Several days ago, we shop for a new washing machine. There are two choices, the traditional type and the high efficient type. The traditional type cost 350 dollars and the high efficient type cost 900 dollars. From the labels on the washers, the annual energy cost of the traditional type is 71 dollars, and the annual energy cost of the efficient type is 35 dollars. Therefore the annual energy saving from the efficient type is 36 dollars. However, the energy cost, or more generally, the resource cost of making an efficient washer is much higher. Since resource consumption is highly correlated with monetary value, we can, as a first approximation, assume to resource consumption in manufacturing a high efficient washer is 900-350 = 650 dollars higher than the traditional type. How long we need to use the high efficient washer to recoup its higher capital cost? The calculation depends on how one discounts future. But even with zero discounting, it will take 650/36 = 18 years. Few can use a washing machine for 18 years. Therefore, the high efficient washer ends up consuming more resources instead of saving. Under what kind of conditions the use of high efficient washer will be cost effective? It is when one use the machine much more often than before. For example, if one use the machine 6 times more often than the average, the time to recoup higher initial capital cost is 3 years. Therefore, only when one use more energy, the efficient machine becomes truly efficient.
There is, moreover, this most serious and yet obvious difference to be noted. A farm, however far pushed, will under proper cultivation continue to yield for ever a constant crop. But in a mine there is no reproduction; the produce once pushed to the utmost will soon begin to fail and sink towards zero. So far, then, as our wealth and progress depend upon the superior command of coal we must not only cease to progress as before – we must begin a retrograde career. (p. 201)
The following statement gives the amounts of coal raised about the years 1858-1860, in the chief coal-producing countries: --- (p. 320)
|
Annual production (Tons) |
|
80,042,698 |
|
14,333,922 |
British American Possessions |
1,500,000 |
|
250,000 |
|
12,000,000 |
|
8,900,000 |
|
7,900,000 |
|
1,500,000 |
|
1,162,900 |
|
300,000 |
|
2,000,000 |
From the above table, the decline of
|
Annual production |
Thousands of Tons |
|
|
1875 |
1889 |
1903 |
|
133,306 |
176,917 |
230,334 |
|
46,686 |
126,098 |
319,068 |
|
929 |
2,373 |
7,140 |
|
1,362 |
4,544 |
8,535 |
|
648 |
2,045 |
7,438 |
|
47,756 |
83,614 |
159,846 |
|
16,686 |
23,915 |
34,345 |
|
14,771 |
19,552 |
23,529 |
|
1,674 |
6,107 |
17,522 |
|
12,854 |
24,923 |
39,528 |
Total world’s output |
277,531 |
474,230 |
863,650 |
From the above table, we understand why
And our anxiety must be indefinitely increased in reflecting that, while other countries mostly subsist upon the annual and ceaseless income of the harvest, we are drawing more and more upon a capital which yields no annual interest, but once turned to light and heat and motive power, is gone for ever into space. (p. 412)
Are we wise in allowing the commerce of this country to rise beyond the point at which it cannot be long maintained? (p. 454)
After all, commerce is but the means to an end --- the
diffusion of civilization and wealth. To allow commerce to expand until the
source of civilization is exhausted is like killing the goose to get the golden
egg. Is the immediate creation of the greatest possible
The alternatives before us are simple. Our empire and race already comprise one-fifth of the world’s population; and by our plantation of new States, by our guardianship of the seas, by our penetrating commerce, by our just laws and firm constitution, and above all by the dissemination of our new arts, we stimulate the progress of mankind in a degree not to be measured. If we lavishly and boldly push forward in the creation of our riches, both material and intellectual, it is hard to over-estimate the pitch of beneficial influence to which we may attain in the present. But the maintenance of such a position is physically impossible. We have to make the momentous choice between brief but true greatness and longer continued mediocrity. (p. 460)
~~~~~~~~~
Some thought on what determines population size.
Population of
Year |
Population |
Numerical increase for ten years |
Rate of increase per cent for ten years |
1701 |
6,121,525 |
|
|
1711 |
6,252,105 |
130,580 |
2 |
1721 |
6,252,750 |
645 |
0 |
1731 |
6,182,972 |
-69,778 |
-1 |
1741 |
6,153,227 |
-29,745 |
0 |
1751 |
6,335,840 |
182,613 |
3 |
1761 |
6,720,547 |
384,707 |
6 |
1771 |
7,153,494 |
432,847 |
6 |
1781 |
7,573,787 |
420,293 |
6 |
1791 |
8,255,617 |
681,830 |
9 |
1801 |
8,892,536 |
636,919 |
11 |
1811 |
10,164,256 |
1,271,720 |
14 |
1821 |
12,000,236 |
1,835,980 |
18 |
1831 |
13,896,797 |
1,896,561 |
16 |
1841 |
15,914,148 |
2,007,351 |
14 |
1851 |
17,927,609 |
2,007,461 |
13 |
1861 |
20,066,224 |
2,138,615 |
12 |
1871 |
22,712,266 |
2,646,042 |
13 |
1881 |
25,974,439 |
3,262,173 |
14 |
1891 |
29,002,525 |
3,028,086 |
12 |
1901 |
32,527,843 |
3,525,318 |
12 |
How to understand the population change of
(p. 384) It was Abraham Darby who revived the forgotten
method of smelting with pit-coal. The earliest adventurers in the process, we
have seen, were Germans, and it is curious that the success of the Darby family
was founded upon foreign experience. The eldest Abraham Darby went over to
There is much uncertainty and discrepancy concerning the history of the Coalbrookdale Works. Scrivennor, in his History of the Iron Trade, represents pit-coal as used in 1713. Dr. Percy, on the other hand, describes the younger Abraham Darby as first employing raw coal in the smelting furnace between the years 1730 and 1735.
In his first successful experiment he is said to have watched the filling of his furnace for six days and nights uninterruptedly, falling into a deep sleep when he saw the molten iron running forth. The success of the work was probably secured by the erection of a water-wheel of twenty-four feet diameter, capable of giving a powerful blast. But water was scarce, and a fire-engine, or old atmospheric steam-engine, was set up to pump back the water from the lower to the upper mill-pond. Here is one of those significant instances which teach us the power of coal and the interdependence of arts. Employed in this engine as a source of motive power, it enabled coal to be also used in the smelting-furnace. And this is the typical of the iron trade, as it is of other trades to the present day; for our iron industry in all its developments is as dependant on coal for motive power as for fuel in the furnace.
In
December, 1756, we find the works “at the top pinnacle of prosperity, twenty or
twenty-two tons per week, and sold off as fast as made, at profit enough.” And
from this time and from this success arose
The subsequent history of the iron trade is best to be read in the growth of its produce. (p. 386)
Compare the dates of mass iron production the population
growth in